
quarta-feira, 28 de abril de 2010
Pavilhão de Portugal 葡萄牙 na Expo Xangai 2010- paredes de cortiça

terça-feira, 27 de abril de 2010
Sair do Nuclear_No Weapons_No Uranium_No Waste - Eis o meu vídeo-grito já no distante 2007
Ver e ler aqui a lista dos 10 locais mais poluídos do Mundo Relatório 2007 do Blacksmith Institute, publicado em Setembro desse ano, CHERNOBYL, UKRAINE

segunda-feira, 26 de abril de 2010
Chernobyl 24 anos depois desta tragédia - quase um milhão de pessoas morreram, são dados do novo livro
![]() |
The Chernobyl nuclear reactor was destroyed by an explosion and fire April 26, 1986. (Photo issued by Soviet authorities) |
domingo, 25 de abril de 2010
São trabalhadores precários que fazem o trabalho sujo e mais perigoso nas centrais nucleares
Chamam-lhes 'jumpers', os que mergulham para dentro do reactor. Ou nómadas do nuclear", lê-se no Alias, o suplemento semanal do diário italiano Il Manifesto.
Empregados por subcontratantes da EDF, GDF-Suez ou Areva, as empresas que gerem as centrais, "incorporam 80% das doses colectivas anuais de radiações ionizantes produzidas pelo parque nuclear francês".
A revista explica que a doutrina do “risco zero” em matéria de protecção das radiações foi progressivamente abandonada, trocada pela muito mais leve ALARA (As Low As Reasonably Acceptable, o mais baixo razoavelmente aceitável).
Vários destes "nómadas nucleares" apresentaram queixa contra os seus empregadores devido às consequências da sua exposição às radiações; mas não tiveram seguimento, porque a prescrição para os acidentes do trabalho no domínio nuclear é de dez anos, "o tempo de incubar a doença e de ocultar as causas que a provocaram", sublinha o Alias.
Entretanto descobri uma entrevista, da Global Subsidies Initiative (GSI) a Doug Koplow, fundador do Earth Track (obrigatório ler).
Nela refere que a indústria nuclear é altamente subsidiada, e que mesmo se esta indústria reduz as emissões de CO2, trata-se de uma falácia, pois os custos são muito elevados.Refere o exemplo do fiasco da mais moderna central nuclear na Finlândia [ler aqui notícia mais detalhada].
O especialista denuncia também a ligação entre o nuclear civil e a proliferação de armamento nuclear.
Ainda de acordo com Doug Koplow a direcção correcta a dar aos mercados é investir em várias outras fontes alternativas de energia e melhorar a eficiência energética.
sábado, 24 de abril de 2010
Ainda não temos um Memorial das vítimas do fascismo e da repressão da PIDE em Portugal
«Tarrafal: memórias do Campo da Morte Lenta»

Domingo, 25 de Abril, às 18H30, no Pequeno Auditório da Culturgest
(Edifício da Caixa Geral de Depósitos, Campo Pequeno, Lisboa)
sexta-feira, 23 de abril de 2010
Privatizações na ferrovia
O Governo Sócrates incluiu no programa de estabilidade e crescimento privatizações na ferrovia: da EMEF (Empresa de Manutenção e Equipamento Ferroviário), da CP e a concessão de linhas.
O transporte ferroviário em Portugal está, actualmente, subdividido em várias empresas, a maioria públicas: a Refer, responsável das linhas; a CP, que gere o transporte ferroviário de passageiros; a CP Carga, desde Julho de 2009, que gere o transporte de mercadorias; a EMEF, que gere as oficinas de manutenção do equipamento ferroviário. Duas empresas privadas intervêm também no sector: a Fertagus, pertencente ao grupo Barraqueiro, que explora o comboio de passageiros da ponte 25 de Abril, e a Takargo, do grupo Mota-Engil, que explora o transporte de mercadorias.
Neste dossier, os artigos Privatização na ferrovia: Privatização da CP - Regresso a 1949: fragmentação e concorrência nos Transportes Públicos do deputado Heitor de Sousa, O Estado fica sem os anéis e sem os dedos de António Gomes, trabalhador da EMEF, e Intenção de privatizar a ferrovia não é nova, de Manuel Sabino, trabalhador da Refer, debruçam-se sobre a situação da ferrovia em Portugal, as privatizações desejadas pelo capital privado e as consequências para os trabalhadores e as populações.
O texto A Europa ferroviária: "revitalização" ou destruição metódica dos meios públicos?, do grupo dos transportes da Attac França, denuncia a "liberalização" do transporte ferroviário na Europa, mostra as contradições que envolve e assinala que a separação da gestão das linhas da gestão das infra-estruturas é um mecanismo artificial, com o único objectivo de avançar com as privatizações no transporte ferroviário.
Incluímos também o texto do socialista francês Jean Jaurés Serviços públicos e classe operária escrito em 1911, após um desastre ferroviário numa empresa recém nacionalizada, e que apesar dos seus quase cem anos, mostra uma candente actualidade.
Os textos O caos dos caminhos de ferro britânicos de Marc Nussbaumer e A Privatização tem sido um desastre de Ken Livingstone debruçam-se sobre a desastrosa privatização dos transportes ferroviários na Grã-Bretanha.
Em Bloco quer esclarecimentos sobre privatizações da CP e da EMEF noticiamos as perguntas feitas pelo grupo parlamentar do Bloco ao Governo sobre as privatizações da CP e da EMEF.
Por fim, lembramos duas excelentes obras cinematográficas: o filme "The Navigators" de Ken Loach, sobre os efeitos na vida dos trabalhadores da privatização da ferrovia britânica, e o documentário "Pare, escute, olhe" de Jorge Pelicano, sobre a abandonada Linha do Tua. Incluímos ainda o vídeo A grande venda também sobre as consequências da privatização da British Rail.
Dossier organizado por Carlos Santos 18.04.10 . Fotos do transporte ferroviário português de Paulete Matos.
Fui alertado por Vitor Silva, que há cerca de um ano entrevistou António Alves, uma pessoa que tem deixado alguns bons contributos sobre esta temática em alguns blogues.
A conversa centrou-se mais na ferrovia no norte do país mas falou-se também na ligação com Espanha e as necessidades a nivel de bitolas (nem tanto na Península Ibérica mas mais na ligação à Europa) mas também nas diferenças que existem a nivel de sinalizações, electrificação das redes,etc.
Podemos ouvir a entrevista aqui

quinta-feira, 22 de abril de 2010
Dê uma mão para o planeta

quarta-feira, 21 de abril de 2010
E porque não um cluster de cientistas portugueses produzirem um contra-manifesto?
1. para evitar que uma vez mais senhores como Henrique Neto, que na TV vem defender a política energética de Salazar (!!) e o primado das barragens - e Carlos Pimenta desmentiu-o e bem informando que os preços das energias por via hídrica são mais baixos porque não contabilizam o carbono e quanto às tecnologias, Portugal tem neste momento vantagens tecnológicas;
2. para aliviar e não atribuir excessivas responsabilidades às associações ambientalistas;
3. para retirar espaço de mediatização de saudosistas do fascismo, niilistas climáticos nacionais e dos defensores de mais barragens e nuclear;
Pergunto porque não um grupo de 100 ou mais cientistas do clima, energias, da mobilidade e economistas pós-carbono nacionais produzam um manifesto? Uma boa base de partida é a postagem do Henrique Santos ou eventualmente outra que possa surgir.
Resumo conferência de imprensa apresentação do “Manifesto por uma nova política energética em Portugal” (e respectivo sítio)
Reações da APREN-Associação Portuguesa de Energias Renováveis ao Manifesto
Documentos Recomendados
Relatório Comissão Europeia que arrasa o Programa Nacional de Barragens [tradução e resumo]Relatório Comissão Europeia que arrasa o Programa Nacional de Barragens
[documento integral- Inglês]
terça-feira, 20 de abril de 2010
Imagens e vídeos da acção da Greenpeace: autocarro por uma Europa Livre de Transgénicos

segunda-feira, 19 de abril de 2010
Reportagem das Manifestações "Alguém quer arroz transgénico?" no Porto e em Lisboa

Foto da Manifestação no Porto, de Manuela Araújo
Em Lisboa, diversos manifestantes estiveram reunidos na Praça do Rossio contra a importação e comercialização de arroz transgénico na União Europeia.
Segundo a Plataforma Transgénicos Fora, o Ministério da Agricultura deve ser chamado ainda em 2010 para votar em Bruxelas a proposta de aprovação para importação e comercialização da primeira variedade de arroz transgénico na União Europeia, o que seria também o primeiro transgénico dirigido essencialmente ao consumo humano.
Advertem ainda para o facto desta eventual permissão ter como efeito um efectivo impulsionar da produção deste arroz, ainda não produzido, em países mais vulneráveis ao lobby industrial e com menos preocupações de protecção ambiental. “O arroz sem transgénicos irá tornar-se uma coisa do passado”.
Para a Plataforma Transgénicos Fora e as entidades que a compõem acreditam que só é possível salvaguardar um futuro com arroz tradicional se for chumbado o pedido da Bayer de introduzir arroz transgénico na União Europeia. [fonte]

domingo, 18 de abril de 2010
Química divertida: Oxigen
In this brief two minute video by Christopher Hendryx we do in fact learn some great facts about Oxygen. Like all great lessons there is just enough entertainment mixed in with the knowledge to make sure we all pay attention. Be sure to notice the fantastic 50’s style narration. It definitely makes this video perfect!
sábado, 17 de abril de 2010
Hoje é dia de comer arroz doce!
Hoje, sábado, às 15h, no Rossio ou nos Aliados, é a altura de lembrar ao Ministro da Agricultura a favor de que interesses deve votar em Bruxelas quando o dossier do arroz transgénico LL62 estiver no rol [leia o comunicado de imprensa da Plataforma de hoje, dia 17.04.10]
Lembre-se que depois da aprovação é tarde de mais para protestar - o momento certo é agora!
sexta-feira, 16 de abril de 2010
Crónica Building a Green Economy, por Paul Krugman

But is it possible to make drastic cuts in greenhouse-gas emissions without destroying our economy?
Environmental Econ 101
If there’s a single central insight in economics, it’s this: There are mutual gains from transactions between consenting adults. If the going price of widgets is $10 and I buy a widget, it must be because that widget is worth more than $10 to me. If you sell a widget at that price, it must be because it costs you less than $10 to make it. So buying and selling in the widget market works to the benefit of both buyers and sellers. More than that, some careful analysis shows that if there is effective competition in the widget market, so that the price ends up matching the number of widgets people want to buy to the number of widgets other people want to sell, the outcome is to maximize the total gains to producers and consumers. Free markets are “efficient” — which, in economics-speak as opposed to plain English, means that nobody can be made better off without making someone else worse off.
One way to deal with negative externalities is to make rules that prohibit or at least limit behavior that imposes especially high costs on others. That’s what we did in the first major wave of environmental legislation in the early 1970s: cars were required to meet emission standards for the chemicals that cause smog, factories were required to limit the volume of effluent they dumped into waterways and so on. And this approach yielded results; America’s air and water became a lot cleaner in the decades that followed.
But while the direct regulation of activities that cause pollution makes sense in some cases, it is seriously defective in others, because it does not offer any scope for flexibility and creativity. Consider the biggest environmental issue of the 1980s — acid rain. Emissions of sulfur dioxide from power plants, it turned out, tend to combine with water downwind and produce flora- and wildlife-destroying sulfuric acid. In 1977, the government made its first stab at confronting the issue, recommending that all new coal-fired plants have scrubbers to remove sulfur dioxide from their emissions. Imposing a tough standard on all plants was problematic, because retrofitting some older plants would have been extremely expensive. By regulating only new plants, however, the government passed up the opportunity to achieve fairly cheap pollution control at plants that were, in fact, easy to retrofit. Short of a de facto federal takeover of the power industry, with federal officials issuing specific instructions to each plant, how was this conundrum to be resolved?
Enter Arthur Cecil Pigou, an early-20th-century British don, whose 1920 book, “The Economics of Welfare,” is generally regarded as the ur-text of environmental economics.
Pigou’s analysis lay mostly fallow for almost half a century, as economists spent their time grappling with issues that seemed more pressing, like the Great Depression. But with the rise of environmental regulation, economists dusted off Pigou and began pressing for a “market-based” approach that gives the private sector an incentive, via prices, to limit pollution, as opposed to a “command and control” fix that issues specific instructions in the form of regulations.
The initial reaction by many environmental activists to this idea was hostile, largely on moral grounds. Pollution, they felt, should be treated like a crime rather than something you have the right to do as long as you pay enough money. Moral concerns aside, there was also considerable skepticism about whether market incentives would actually be successful in reducing pollution. Even today, Pigovian taxes as originally envisaged are relatively rare. The most successful example I’ve been able to find is a Dutch tax on discharges of water containing organic materials.
What has caught on instead is a variant that most economists consider more or less equivalent: a system of tradable emissions permits, a k a cap and trade. In this model, a limited number of licenses to emit a specified pollutant, like sulfur dioxide, are issued. A business that wants to create more pollution than it is licensed for can go out and buy additional licenses from other parties; a firm that has more licenses than it intends to use can sell its surplus. This gives everyone an incentive to reduce pollution, because buyers would not have to acquire as many licenses if they can cut back on their emissions, and sellers can unload more licenses if they do the same. In fact, economically, a cap-and-trade system produces the same incentives to reduce pollution as a Pigovian tax, with the price of licenses effectively serving as a tax on pollution.
In practice there are a couple of important differences between cap and trade and a pollution tax. One is that the two systems produce different types of uncertainty. If the government imposes a pollution tax, polluters know what price they will have to pay, but the government does not know how much pollution they will generate. If the government imposes a cap, it knows the amount of pollution, but polluters do not know what the price of emissions will be. Another important difference has to do with government revenue. A pollution tax is, well, a tax, which imposes costs on the private sector while generating revenue for the government. Cap and trade is a bit more complicated. If the government simply auctions off licenses and collects the revenue, then it is just like a tax. Cap and trade, however, often involves handing out licenses to existing players, so the potential revenue goes to industry instead of the government.
Politically speaking, doling out licenses to industry isn’t entirely bad, because it offers a way to partly compensate some of the groups whose interests would suffer if a serious climate-change policy were adopted. This can make passing legislation more feasible.
These political considerations probably explain why the solution to the acid-rain predicament took the form of cap and trade and why licenses to pollute were distributed free to power companies. It’s also worth noting that the Waxman-Markey bill, a cap-and-trade setup for greenhouse gases that starts by giving out many licenses to industry but puts up a growing number for auction in later years, was actually passed by the House of Representatives last year; it’s hard to imagine a broad-based emissions tax doing the same for many years.
That’s not to say that emission taxes are a complete nonstarter. Some senators have recently floated a proposal for a sort of hybrid solution, with cap and trade for some parts of the economy and carbon taxes for others — mainly oil and gas. The political logic seems to be that the oil industry thinks consumers won’t blame it for higher gas prices if those prices reflect an explicit tax.
In any case, experience suggests that market-based emission controls work. Our recent history with acid rain shows as much. The Clean Air Act of 1990 introduced a cap-and-trade system in which power plants could buy and sell the right to emit sulfur dioxide, leaving it up to individual companies to manage their own business within the new limits. Sure enough, over time sulfur-dioxide emissions from power plants were cut almost in half, at a much lower cost than even optimists expected; electricity prices fell instead of rising. Acid rain did not disappear as a problem, but it was significantly mitigated. The results, it would seem, demonstrated that we can deal with environmental problems when we have to.
So there we have it, right? The emission of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases is a classic negative externality — the “biggest market failure the world has ever seen,” in the words of Nicholas Stern, the author of a report on the subject for the British government. Textbook economics and real-world experience tell us that we should have policies to discourage activities that generate negative externalities and that it is generally best to rely on a market-based approach.
This is an article on climate economics, not climate science. But before we get to the economics, it’s worth establishing three things about the state of the scientific debate.
Second, climate models predicted this well in advance, even getting the magnitude of the temperature rise roughly right. While it’s relatively easy to cook up an analysis that matches known data, it is much harder to create a model that accurately forecasts the future. So the fact that climate modelers more than 20 years ago successfully predicted the subsequent global warming gives them enormous credibility.
Yet that’s not the conclusion you might draw from the many media reports that have focused on matters like hacked e-mail and climate scientists’ talking about a “trick” to “hide” an anomalous decline in one data series or expressing their wish to see papers by climate skeptics kept out of research reviews. The truth, however, is that the supposed scandals evaporate on closer examination, revealing only that climate researchers are human beings, too. Yes, scientists try to make their results stand out, but no data were suppressed. Yes, scientists dislike it when work that they think deliberately obfuscates the issues gets published. What else is new? Nothing suggests that there should not continue to be strong support for climate research.
Serious opposition to cap and trade generally comes in two forms: an argument that more direct action — in particular, a ban on coal-fired power plants — would be more effective and an argument that an emissions tax would be better than emissions trading. (Let’s leave aside those who dismiss climate science altogether and oppose any limits on greenhouse-gas emissions, as well as those who oppose the use of any kind of market-based remedy.) There’s something to each of these positions, just not as much as their proponents think.
When it comes to direct action, you can make the case that economists love markets not wisely but too well, that they are too ready to assume that changing people’s financial incentives fixes every problem. In particular, you can’t put a price on something unless you can measure it accurately, and that can be both difficult and expensive. So sometimes it’s better simply to lay down some basic rules about what people can and cannot do.
Consider auto emissions, for example. Could we or should we charge each car owner a fee proportional to the emissions from his or her tailpipe? Surely not. You would have to install expensive monitoring equipment on every car, and you would also have to worry about fraud. It’s almost certainly better to do what we actually do, which is impose emissions standards on all cars.
Is there a comparable argument to be made for greenhouse-gas emissions? My initial reaction, which I suspect most economists would share, is that the very scale and complexity of the situation requires a market-based solution, whether cap and trade or an emissions tax. After all, greenhouse gases are a direct or indirect byproduct of almost everything produced in a modern economy, from the houses we live in to the cars we drive. Reducing emissions of those gases will require getting people to change their behavior in many different ways, some of them impossible to identify until we have a much better grasp of green technology. So can we really make meaningful progress by telling people specifically what will or will not be permitted? Econ 101 tells us — probably correctly — that the only way to get people to change their behavior appropriately is to put a price on emissions so this cost in turn gets incorporated into everything else in a way that reflects ultimate environmental impacts.
When shoppers go to the grocery store, for example, they will find that fruits and vegetables from farther away have higher prices than local produce, reflecting in part the cost of emission licenses or taxes paid to ship that produce. When businesses decide how much to spend on insulation, they will take into account the costs of heating and air-conditioning that include the price of emissions licenses or taxes for electricity generation. When electric utilities have to choose among energy sources, they will have to take into account the higher license fees or taxes associated with fossil-fuel consumption. And so on down the line. A market-based system would create decentralized incentives to do the right thing, and that’s the only way it can be done.
That said, some specific rules may be required. James Hansen, the renowned climate scientist who deserves much of the credit for making global warming an issue in the first place, has argued forcefully that most of the climate-change problem comes down to just one thing, burning coal, and that whatever else we do, we have to shut down coal burning over the next couple decades. My economist’s reaction is that a stiff license fee would strongly discourage coal use anyway. But a market-based system might turn out to have loopholes — and their consequences could be dire. So I would advocate supplementing market-based disincentives with direct controls on coal burning.
What about the case for an emissions tax rather than cap and trade? There’s no question that a straightforward tax would have many advantages over legislation like Waxman-Markey, which is full of exceptions and special situations. But that’s not really a useful comparison: of course an idealized emissions tax looks better than a cap-and-trade system that has already passed the House with all its attendant compromises. The question is whether the emissions tax that could actually be put in place is better than cap and trade. There is no reason to believe that it would be — indeed, there is no reason to believe that a broad-based emissions tax would make it through Congress.
To be fair, Hansen has made an interesting moral argument against cap and trade, one that’s much more sophisticated than the old view that it’s wrong to let polluters buy the right to pollute. What Hansen draws attention to is the fact that in a cap-and-trade world, acts of individual virtue do not contribute to social goals. If you choose to drive a hybrid car or buy a house with a small carbon footprint, all you are doing is freeing up emissions permits for someone else, which means that you have done nothing to reduce the threat of climate change. He has a point. But altruism cannot effectively deal with climate change. Any serious solution must rely mainly on creating a system that gives everyone a self-interested reason to produce fewer emissions. It’s a shame, but climate altruism must take a back seat to the task of getting such a system in place.
The bottom line, then, is that while climate change may be a vastly bigger problem than acid rain, the logic of how to respond to it is much the same. What we need are market incentives for reducing greenhouse-gas emissions — along with some direct controls over coal use — and cap and trade is a reasonable way to create those incentives.
The Cost of Action
Just as there is a rough consensus among climate modelers about the likely trajectory of temperatures if we do not act to cut the emissions of greenhouse gases, there is a rough consensus among economic modelers about the costs of action. That general opinion may be summed up as follows: Restricting emissions would slow economic growth — but not by much. The Congressional Budget Office, relying on a survey of models, has concluded that Waxman-Markey “would reduce the projected average annual rate of growth of gross domestic product between 2010 and 2050 by 0.03 to 0.09 percentage points.” That is, it would trim average annual growth to 2.31 percent, at worst, from 2.4 percent. Over all, the Budget Office concludes, strong climate-change policy would leave the American economy between 1.1 percent and 3.4 percent smaller in 2050 than it would be otherwise.
Such figures typically come from a model that combines all sorts of engineering and marketplace estimates. These will include, for instance, engineers’ best calculations of how much it costs to generate electricity in various ways, from coal, gas and nuclear and solar power at given resource prices. Then estimates will be made, based on historical experience, of how much consumers would cut back their electricity consumption if its price rises. The same process is followed for other kinds of energy, like motor fuel. And the model assumes that everyone makes the best choice given the economic environment — that power generators choose the least expensive means of producing electricity, while consumers conserve energy as long as the money saved by buying less electricity exceeds the cost of using less power in the form either of other spending or loss of convenience. After all this analysis, it’s possible to predict how producers and consumers of energy will react to policies that put a price on emissions and how much those reactions will end up costing the economy as a whole.
But while it’s unlikely that these models get everything right, it’s a good bet that they overstate rather than understate the economic costs of climate-change action. That is what the experience from the cap-and-trade program for acid rain suggests: costs came in well below initial predictions. And in general, what the models do not and cannot take into account is creativity; surely, faced with an economy in which there are big monetary payoffs for reducing greenhouse-gas emissions, the private sector will come up with ways to limit emissions that are not yet in any model.
Clearly, conservatives abandon all faith in the ability of markets to cope with climate-change policy because they don’t want government intervention. Their stated pessimism about the cost of climate policy is essentially a political ploy rather than a reasoned economic judgment. The giveaway is the strong tendency of conservative opponents of cap and trade to argue in bad faith. That Heritage Foundation broadside accuses the Congressional Budget Office of making elementary logical errors, but if you actually read the office’s report, it’s clear that the foundation is willfully misreading it. Conservative politicians have been even more shameless. The National Republican Congressional Committee, for example, issued multiple press releases specifically citing a study from M.I.T. as the basis for a claim that cap and trade would cost $3,100 per household, despite repeated attempts by the study’s authors to get out the word that the actual number was only about a quarter as much.
But that’s not the same as saying we should. Action will have costs, and these must be compared with the costs of not acting. Before I get to that, however, let me touch on an issue that will become central if we actually do get moving on climate policy: how to get the rest of the world to go along with us.
The China Syndrome
The United States is still the world’s largest economy, which makes the country one of the world’s largest sources of greenhouse gases. But it’s not the largest. China, which burns much more coal per dollar of gross domestic product than the United States does, overtook us by that measure around three years ago. Over all, the advanced countries — the rich man’s club comprising Europe, North America and Japan — account for only about half of greenhouse emissions, and that’s a fraction that will fall over time. In short, there can’t be a solution to climate change unless the rest of the world, emerging economies in particular, participates in a major way.
A carbon tariff would be a tax levied on imported goods proportional to the carbon emitted in the manufacture of those goods. Suppose that China refuses to reduce emissions, while the United States adopts policies that set a price of $100 per ton of carbon emissions. If the United States were to impose such a carbon tariff, any shipment to America of Chinese goods whose production involved emitting a ton of carbon would result in a $100 tax over and above any other duties. Such tariffs, if levied by major players — probably the United States and the European Union — would give noncooperating countries a strong incentive to reconsider their positions.
Needless to say, the actual business of getting cooperative, worldwide action on climate change would be much more complicated and tendentious than this discussion suggests. Yet the problem is not as intractable as you often hear. If the United States and Europe decide to move on climate policy, they almost certainly would be able to cajole and chivvy the rest of the world into joining the effort. We can do this.
The Costs of Inaction
In public discussion, the climate-change skeptics have clearly been gaining ground over the past couple of years, even though the odds have been looking good lately that 2010 could be the warmest year on record. But climate modelers themselves have grown increasingly pessimistic. What were previously worst-case scenarios have become base-line projections, with a number of organizations doubling their predictions for temperature rise over the course of the 21st century. Underlying this new pessimism is increased concern about feedback effects — for example, the release of methane, a significant greenhouse gas, from seabeds and tundra as the planet warms.
At this point, the projections of climate change, assuming we continue business as usual, cluster around an estimate that average temperatures will be about 9 degrees Fahrenheit higher in 2100 than they were in 2000. That’s a lot — equivalent to the difference in average temperatures between New York and central Mississippi. Such a huge change would have to be highly disruptive. And the troubles would not stop there: temperatures would continue to rise.
Furthermore, changes in average temperature will by no means be the whole story. Precipitation patterns will change, with some regions getting much wetter and others much drier. Many modelers also predict more intense storms. Sea levels would rise, with the impact intensified by those storms: coastal flooding, already a major source of natural disasters, would become much more frequent and severe. And there might be drastic changes in the climate of some regions as ocean currents shift. It’s always worth bearing in mind that London is at the same latitude as Labrador; without the Gulf Stream, Western Europe would be barely habitable.
But there are at least two reasons to take sanguine assessments of the consequences of climate change with a grain of salt. One is that, as I have just pointed out, it’s not just a matter of having warmer weather — many of the costs of climate change are likely to result from droughts, flooding and severe storms. The other is that while modern economies may be highly adaptable, the same may not be true of ecosystems.
The last time the earth experienced warming at anything like the pace we now expect was during the Paleocene-Eocene Thermal Maximum, about 55 million years ago, when temperatures rose by about 11 degrees Fahrenheit over the course of around 20,000 years (which is a much slower rate than the current pace of warming). That increase was associated with mass extinctions, which, to put it mildly, probably would not be good for living standards.
So how can we put a price tag on the effects of global warming? The most widely quoted estimates, like those in the Dynamic Integrated Model of Climate and the Economy, known as DICE, used by Yale’s William Nordhaus and colleagues, depend upon educated guesswork to place a value on the negative effects of global warming in a number of crucial areas, especially agriculture and coastal protection, then try to make some allowance for other possible repercussions. Nordhaus has argued that a global temperature rise of 4.5 degrees Fahrenheit — which used to be the consensus projection for 2100 — would reduce gross world product by a bit less than 2 percent.
But what would happen if, as a growing number of models suggest, the actual temperature rise is twice as great? Nobody really knows how to make that extrapolation. For what it’s worth, Nordhaus’s model puts losses from a rise of 9 degrees at about 5 percent of gross world product. Many critics have argued, however, that the cost might be much higher.
First, substantial global warming is already “baked in,” as a result of past emissions and because even with a strong climate-change policy the amount of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere is most likely to continue rising for many years. So even if the nations of the world do manage to take on climate change, we will still have to pay for earlier inaction. As a result, Nordhaus’s loss estimates may overstate the gains from action.
Second, the economic costs from emissions limits would start as soon as the policy went into effect and under most proposals would become substantial within around 20 years. If we don’t act, meanwhile, the big costs would probably come late this century (although some things, like the transformation of the American Southwest into a dust bowl, might come much sooner). So how you compare those costs depends on how much you value costs in the distant future relative to costs that materialize much sooner.
Third, and cutting in the opposite direction, if we don’t take action, global warming won’t stop in 2100: temperatures, and losses, will continue to rise. So if you place a significant weight on the really, really distant future, the case for action is stronger than even the 2100 estimates suggest.
Finally and most important is the matter of uncertainty. We’re uncertain about the magnitude of climate change, which is inevitable, because we’re talking about reaching levels of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere not seen in millions of years. The recent doubling of many modelers’ predictions for 2100 is itself an illustration of the scope of that uncertainty; who knows what revisions may occur in the years ahead. Beyond that, nobody really knows how much damage would result from temperature rises of the kind now considered likely.
You might think that this uncertainty weakens the case for action, but it actually strengthens it. As Harvard’s Martin Weitzman has argued in several influential papers, if there is a significant chance of utter catastrophe, that chance — rather than what is most likely to happen — should dominate cost-benefit calculations. And utter catastrophe does look like a realistic possibility, even if it is not the most likely outcome.
Weitzman argues — and I agree — that this risk of catastrophe, rather than the details of cost-benefit calculations, makes the most powerful case for strong climate policy. Current projections of global warming in the absence of action are just too close to the kinds of numbers associated with doomsday scenarios. It would be irresponsible — it’s tempting to say criminally irresponsible — not to step back from what could all too easily turn out to be the edge of a cliff.
The Ramp Versus the Big Bang
Economists who analyze climate policies agree on some key issues. There is a broad consensus that we need to put a price on carbon emissions, that this price must eventually be very high but that the negative economic effects from this policy will be of manageable size. In other words, we can and should act to limit climate change. But there is a ferocious debate among knowledgeable analysts about timing, about how fast carbon prices should rise to significant levels.
I find it easiest to make sense of the arguments by thinking of policies to reduce carbon emissions as a sort of public investment project: you pay a price now and derive benefits in the form of a less-damaged planet later. And by later, I mean much later; today’s emissions will affect the amount of carbon in the atmosphere decades, and possibly centuries, into the future. So if you want to assess whether a given investment in emissions reduction is worth making, you have to estimate the damage that an additional ton of carbon in the atmosphere will do, not just this year but for a century or more to come; and you also have to decide how much weight to place on harm that will take a very long time to materialize.
The policy-ramp advocates argue that the damage done by an additional ton of carbon in the atmosphere is fairly low at current concentrations; the cost will not get really large until there is a lot more carbon dioxide in the air, and that won’t happen until late this century. And they argue that costs that far in the future should not have a large influence on policy today. They point to market rates of return, which indicate that investors place only a small weight on the gains or losses they expect in the distant future, and argue that public policies, including climate policies, should do the same.
The big-bang advocates argue that government should take a much longer view than private investors. Stern, in particular, argues that policy makers should give the same weight to future generations’ welfare as we give to those now living. Moreover, the proponents of fast action hold that the damage from emissions may be much larger than the policy-ramp analyses suggest, either because global temperatures are more sensitive to greenhouse-gas emissions than previously thought or because the economic damage from a large rise in temperatures is much greater than the guesstimates in the climate-ramp models.
As a professional economist, I find this debate painful. There are smart, well-intentioned people on both sides — some of them, as it happens, old friends and mentors of mine — and each side has scored some major points. Unfortunately, we can’t just declare it an honorable draw, because there’s a decision to be made.
The Political Atmosphere
As I’ve mentioned, the House has already passed Waxman-Markey, a fairly strong bill aimed at reducing greenhouse-gas emissions. It’s not as strong as what the big-bang advocates propose, but it appears to move faster than the policy-ramp proposals. But the vote on Waxman-Markey, which was taken last June, revealed a starkly divided Congress. Only 8 Republicans voted in favor of it, while 44 Democrats voted against. And the odds are that it would not pass if it were brought up for a vote today.
Oh, and a snowy winter on the East Coast of the U.S. has given climate skeptics a field day, even though globally this has been one of the warmest winters on record.
Saiba tudo sobre Via Campesina e Caso Syngenta: transgénicos, agrotóxicos e violência.

Novo relatório agora publicado pela ONG Terra de Direitos (Março de 2010)
Ficha Ténica – Caso Syngenta
Nome: Syngenta Mata: transgênicos, agrotóxicos e violência
Localização: Município de Santa Tereza do Oeste, Paraná.
Resumo:
Este caso traz diversas violações de direitos humanos protagonizadas pela Syngenta Seeds, empresa transnacional do agronegócio que produz sementes transgênicas e agrotóxicos. As ações violadoras compreendem assassinato, violência física e moral contra trabalhadores rurais sem terra, manutenção de milícias privadas armadas, realização de despejos forçados sem determinação judicial, adulteração de venenos, contaminação do solo com agrotóxicos, contaminação da agrobiodiversidade com sementes transgênicas, criminalização dos movimentos sociais, entre outras tantas ações.
A Terra de Direitos tem atuação direta contra a transnacional desde a denúncia feita ao IBAMA, em 2006, junto com a Via Campesina. O motivo principal foi a realização de experimentos ilegais com sementes transgênicas na Zona de Amortecimento de Parque Nacional do Iguaçu, cidade de Santa Tereza do Oeste, oeste do Paraná. A empresa foi multada em um milhão de reais,
Com o objetivo de denunciar as violações de direitos humanos pela Syngenta, o Movimento dos Trabalhadores Rurais Sem Terra ocupou a área. Após a ocupação, os trabalhadores foram atacados por uma milícia privada armada, contratada pela Syngenta, ocasionado lesões corporais em mais de 10 pessoas e a morte do trabalhador rural sem terra Valmir Motta de Oliveira, também conhecido como Keno.
O caso foi denunciado em todo o Brasil, em tribunais internacionais e também no país de origem da empresa. Além das questões processuais sobre o uso de milícias, a morte de Keno e o plantio ilegal de transgênico, o caso Syngenta Seeds levanta a polêmica sobre a atuação das empresas transnacionais, que contam com muitos incentivos, possuem muitos direitos, mas têm poucas obrigações, o que torna muito difícil responsabilizá-las pelas violações de direitos.
Contexto Histórico:
Desde 1998 a filial brasileira da empresa suíça Syngenta Seeds mantinha um campo experimental, com área de 127 hectares, na cidade de Santa Tereza do Oeste, a 6 km do Parque Nacional do Iguaçu. Desrespeitando a legislação ambiental e o Plano de Manejo do Parque, a empresa cometeu uma série de crimes ambientais, realizando experimentos com soja e milho geneticamente modificados , o que, em março de 2006, levou o IBAMA a multá-la no valor de 1 milhão de reais.
Para denunciar os crimes cometidos pela Syngenta, os militantes da Via Campesina ocuparam a estação experimental, no dia 14 de março de 2006, durante a realização da Convenção de Biodiversidade Biológica (COP/MOP) no Brasil. A ocupação do Campo Experimental teve ampla repercussão e apoio internacional, inclusive com a organização de uma visita de ambientalistas de mais de 15 países à área ocupada, durante a Convenção.
As 70 famílias permaneceram na área até novembro de 2006, quando o Estado do Paraná cumpriu a liminar de reintegração de posse expedida pela Justiça Estadual de Cascavel. Mesmo assim, as famílias retornaram ao local depois que a área foi desapropriada pelo Governo do Estado para a criação de um Centro de Agroecologia. Após 16 meses de resistência, no dia 18 de julho de 2007, cumprindo ordem judicial, as famílias se deslocaram para o assentamento Olga Benário, também em Santa Tereza do Oeste.
Em outubro de 2007, cerca de 200 trabalhadores da Via Campesina reocuparam a Fazenda Experimental após rumores de que a Syngenta retomaria os experimentos ilegais, o que exporia as lavouras convencionais próximas ao Parque ao perigo da contaminação por transgênicos. Além disso, a Syngenta não havia pago a multa aplicada pelo IBAMA.
Horas depois da reocupação, mais de 30 homens fortemente armados e vestidos com uniforme da empresa “NF Segurança” invadiram a área e dispararam contra os trabalhadores. Após balearem Valmir Mota, o “Keno”, com um tiro na perna, o executaram a queima roupa com um tiro no peito. A milícia tentou ainda executar a trabalhadora Isabel do Nascimento de Souza com um tiro na cabeça, o que resultou na perda de um de seus olhos e da mobilidade da parte esquerda do corpo. Outros três trabalhadores saíram feridos e um segurança foi morto por integrantes da própria milícia que atiravam desordenadamente, conforme indicou a polícia. A “NF Segurança” atuava de forma irregular naquela região, articulada com a Sociedade Rural do Oeste (SRO) e o Movimento dos Produtores Rurais (MPR), representantes dos latifundiários locais.
Ações desenvolvidas:
A Via Campesina exigiu punição dos responsáveis pelos crimes – principalmente os mandantes -, a desarticulação da milícia armada na região e o fechamento imediato da empresa de segurança NF. A preocupação foi também de garantir segurança e proteção a vida de outros dirigentes, alvos preferenciais do ataque, bem como de todos os trabalhadores da Via Campesina na região.
Uma ação penal foi instaurada em decorrência dos crimes cometidos durante a ação da empresa NF Segurança contra trabalhadores e trabalhadoras rurais. Nenhuma pessoa da transnacional Syngenta foi denunciada, assim como nenhum mandante. Apenas o proprietário da NF segurança e nove pistoleiros foram denunciados pelos crimes cometidos.
Inesperadamente, o Ministério Público da Paraná denunciou oito integrantes do MST pelo assassinato do segurança, de Keno e por lesões corporais cometidas pelos pistoleiros da NF Segurança contra os próprios trabalhadores. O MP entendeu – e o Judiciário aceitou a tese – que os trabalhadores são responsáveis pelos crimes única e exclusivamente por terem realizado a ocupação da estação experimental da Syngenta. Diz o MP que os trabalhadores, ao realizarem a ocupação, assumiram o risco de serem vítimas de reação armada da Syngenta e por esse motivo devem responder criminalmente pela violência que sofreram.
A ampla divulgação das informações desdobrou-se também em campanhas, como a lançada pela Assessoria e Serviços a Projetos de Agricultura Alternativa (AS-PTA) – “Por um Brasil livre de transgênicos”-, que tem se mostrado instrumento efetivo de embate político.
A repercussão institucional dessas ações resultou, ainda, em audiência pública na Câmara dos Deputados, no dia 16/04/08, por iniciativa da Comissão de Legislação Participativa, para debater propostas de enfrentamento dos crimes cometidos contra trabalhadores rurais no Paraná. A Terra de Direitos apresentou ao Ministério da Justiça uma representação contra a Sociedade Rural do Oeste e NF Empresa de Segurança, requisitando o imediato fechamento e a responsabilização de seus sócios. Em junho de 2008, durante o curso da “Operação Varredura VII”, a empresa de segurança teve a licença de funcionamento cassada pela Polícia Federal, por atuar clandestinamente. (Leia: “PF autua 53 empresas clandestinas de segurança ”).
No plano internacional, o relator especial da Organização das Nações Unidas (ONU) sobre Execuções Sumárias, Arbitrárias e Extrajudiciais, Philip Alston, recebeu em novembro de 2007 um documento sobre o caso. O relatório – entregue conjuntamente com integrantes da Via Campesina e do MST – denunciou a atuação de milícias armadas no campo e sustentou que a empresa NF Segurança era apenas uma fachada legal para um grupo paramilitar a serviço de fazendeiros da região (Leia mais). O caso passou a receber amplo apoio internacional, tendo centenas de pessoas participado de protestos em repúdio ao assassinato de Keno em diversos países, como Coréia do Sul, Indonésia, Congo, Espanha, no Chile, no Canadá, na Croácia e na Venezuela.
Henry Saragih, coordenador-geral da Via Campesina, convocou mobilizações pelos direitos dos trabalhadores rurais e de repúdio à Syngenta enquanto, na Suíça a organização de agricultores Uniterre solicitou à presidente do país, Micheline Calmy-Rey, o acompanhamento do caso no Brasil. Essas ações foram fortalecidas pela atuação de parlamentares suíços, que requisitaram providências da Syngenta para reparar os danos sofridos pelas vítimas do ataque e medidas a serem adotadas em relação à filial brasileira, para evitar novos eventos análogos. Por conta disso, em março de 2008, o embaixador da Suíça no Brasil, Rudolf Bärfuss, pediu oficialmente desculpas à viúva de Keno, Iris Oliveira, em nome de seu país.
Outra importante tática de incidência foi o diálogo com acionistas minoritários da empresa, que durante a Assembléia geral da empresa, em abril de 2008, cobraram providências para uma solução pacífica do conflito, para que a empresa respeitasse as leis brasileiras e assumisse sua responsabilidade frente ao ocorrido. É provável que a doação da área experimental feita ao Estado do Paraná, em outubro do mesmo ano, tenha decorrido dessa movimentação.
A Anistia Internacional, por sua vez, a partir da interlocução com a Terra de Direitos, lançou um apelo pedindo providências dos órgãos competentes pela morte do dirigente do MST. Além dela, mais de 200 entidades se manifestaram publicamente, no mundo inteiro, contra a ação da Syngenta no Paraná.
O conjunto desta estratégia jurídica resultou na apreciação do caso pelo Tribunal Permanente dos Povos, instância política que durante sessão na cidade de Lima, Peru, em maio de 2008, reconheceu a responsabilidade da empresa Syngenta Seeds Ltda. pela violação de Direitos Humanos. Apesar de toda a mobilização em torno do caso, os processos judiciais ainda estão em andamento no Brasil.
Situação do(s) processo(s):
A complexidade do caso se evidencia nas três classes de processos a ele associadas:
a) processos referentes à desapropriação da área;
b) processos referentes à multa administrativa recebida pela empresa e;
c) processos criminais referentes às agressões e homicídios perpetrados pela empresa de segurança NF, contrata pela Syngenta.
a) Em novembro de 2006, o Governo do Estado do Paraná, por meio do Decreto nº 7487, publicado em 09 de novembro de 2006, desapropriou a Estação Experimental para instalar um centro de agroecologia no local e tentar recuperar os danos ao meio ambiente provocados pela empresa. Todavia, em janeiro de 2007, a Syngenta conseguiu uma liminar no Tribunal de Justiça do Paraná que suspendeu os efeitos do Decreto de Desapropriação da área, anulado em janeiro de 2008. Apesar disso e em decorrência da publicidade negativa gerada pelo caso, a Syngenta decidiu doar a área ao Estado do Paraná, em outubro de 2008. Finalmente, no dia 05/12/2009, cumpriu-se o projeto anunciado com a inauguração no local do Centro de Ensino e Pesquisa em Agroecologia Waldir Motta de Oliveira e o Monumento Keno Vive.
b) A Syngenta contestou judicialmente a multa de um milhão de reais. Em novembro de 2007 o juiz proferiu sentença favorável ao IBAMA, confirmando a multa. A Syngenta, não satisfeita, recorreu da decisão. O Tribunal Regional Federal da 4ª Região, em janeiro de 2007, deu provimento à apelação, anulando a multa e alegando o cumprimento dos pareceres emitidos pela Comissão Técnica Nacional de Biossegurança – CTNBio – em detrimento da legislação ambiental vigente. O INCRA recorreu dessa decisão, que ainda deve ser analisada pelo STF e STJ.
c) Tramita perante a 1ª Vara Criminal de Cascavel a Ação Penal nº 2007.3982-4, ainda em fase de instrução, aguardando oitiva de diversas testemunhas. O Ministério Público acusa a empresa de segurança NF, contratada pela Syngenta, de ser uma quadrilha armada com o objetivo de realizar despejos ilegais em acampamentos de trabalhadores rurais que lutam pela reforma agrária. Vale notar que, a despeito de todas as evidências e das manifestações de diversos grupos apontando o envolvendo da Syngenta com os fatos, a empresa não foi diretamente relacionada aos crimes no curso da ação penal. O processo , porém, tem sido usado principalmente para criminalizar os trabalhadores, que, apesar de vítimas da violência, também foram denunciados como réus, dos quais a Terra de Direitos atua como defensora.
Opine sobre este caso: Quer dar sua opinião sobre este caso? Entre em contato conosco: comunicacao@terradedireitos.org.br
LEIA MAIS:
29/04/08: Parlamentares Suiços e Acionistas solicitam explicações à Syngenta por crimes cometidos no Brasil
15/04/08: Ataques a camponeses por milícias armadas se proliferam no Paraná
20/12/07: CASO SYNGENTA: Ação Penal criminaliza trabalhadores rurais e não responsabiliza mandantes
11/12/07: Ministério Público criminaliza trabalhadores da Via Campesina – vítimas de ataque
04/12/07: Crimes do Agronegócio – Ação de milícia contratada pela Syngenta mata militante do MST no Paraná
04/12/07: Anistia Internacional pede providências pela morte de Sem Terra na Syngenta
23/10/07: Organizações querem rigor nas investigações e responsabilização da Syngenta pelos crimes
22/10/07: Nota a imprensa: Milícia armada ataca acampamento da Via Campesina e executa militante
18/05/09: As milícias privadas e os seletivos olhos da “democracia” – artigo de Roberto Efrem Filho.
20/10/08: Relatores de Direitos Humanos concluem relatório sobre assassinato de Keno
23/10/2007: Polícia Federal diz que empresa de segurança NF tem contrato com Sociedade Rural do Oeste
Confira e baixe as tabelas e textos complementares nos arquivos anexados.
Anexo | Tamanho |
---|
